You signed in with another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You signed out in another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You switched accounts on another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.Dismiss alert
Copy file name to clipboardExpand all lines: lectures/cagan_adaptive.md
+44-48Lines changed: 44 additions & 48 deletions
Original file line number
Diff line number
Diff line change
@@ -43,7 +43,7 @@ Instead of the "perfect foresight" or "rational expectations" version of the mod
43
43
44
44
It combines these components:
45
45
46
-
* a demand function for real money balances that says asserts that the logarithm of the quantity of real balances demanded depends inversely on the public's expected rate of inflation
46
+
* a demand function for real money balances that asserts that the logarithm of the quantity of real balances demanded depends inversely on the public's expected rate of inflation
47
47
48
48
* an **adaptive expectations** model that describes how the public's anticipated rate of inflation responds to past values of actual inflation
49
49
@@ -53,12 +53,12 @@ It combines these components:
53
53
54
54
Our model stays quite close to Cagan's original specification.
55
55
56
-
As in the {doc}`present values <pv>` and {doc}`consumption smoothing<cons_smooth>` lectures, the only linear algebra operations that we'll be using are matrix multplication and matrix inversion.
56
+
As in the {doc}`present values <pv>` and {doc}`consumption smoothing<cons_smooth>` lectures, the only linear algebra operations that we'll be using are matrix multiplication and matrix inversion.
57
57
58
58
To facilitate using linear matrix algebra as our principal mathematical tool, we'll use a finite horizon version of
59
59
the model.
60
60
61
-
## Structure of the Model
61
+
## Structure of the model
62
62
63
63
Let
64
64
@@ -75,13 +75,13 @@ The demand for real balances $\exp\left(\frac{m_t^d}{p_t}\right)$ is governed by
This equation asserts that the demand for real balances
82
82
is inversely related to the public's expected rate of inflation.
83
83
84
-
Equating the logarithm $m_t^d$ of the demand for money to the logarithm $m_t$ of the supply of money in equation {eq}`eq:caganmd` and solving for the logarithm $p_t$
84
+
Equating the logarithm $m_t^d$ of the demand for money to the logarithm $m_t$ of the supply of money in equation {eq}`eq:caganmd_ad` and solving for the logarithm $p_t$
85
85
of the price level gives
86
86
87
87
$$
@@ -105,9 +105,9 @@ $$
105
105
$$ (eq:adaptexpn)
106
106
107
107
As exogenous inputs into the model, we take initial conditions $m_0, \pi_0^*$
108
-
and a money growth sequence $\vec \mu = \{\mu_t\}_{t=0}^T$.
108
+
and a money growth sequence $\mu = \{\mu_t\}_{t=0}^T$.
109
109
110
-
As endogenous outputs of our model we want to find sequences $\vec \pi = \{\pi_t\}_{t=0}^T, \vec p = \{p_t\}_{t=0}^T$ as functions of the endogenous inputs.
110
+
As endogenous outputs of our model we want to find sequences $\pi = \{\pi_t\}_{t=0}^T, p = \{p_t\}_{t=0}^T$ as functions of the endogenous inputs.
111
111
112
112
We'll do some mental experiments by studying how the model outputs vary as we vary
113
113
the model inputs.
@@ -148,10 +148,10 @@ $$
148
148
Write this equation as
149
149
150
150
$$
151
-
A \vec \pi^* = (1-\lambda) B \vec \pi + \vec \pi_0^*
151
+
A \pi^* = (1-\lambda) B \pi + \pi_0^*
152
152
$$ (eq:eq1)
153
153
154
-
where the $(T+2) \times (T+2) $matrix $A$, the $(T+2)\times (T+1)$ matrix $B$, and the vectors $\vec \pi^* , \vec \pi_0, \pi_0^*$
154
+
where the $(T+2) \times (T+2) $matrix $A$, the $(T+2)\times (T+1)$ matrix $B$, and the vectors $\pi^* , \pi_0, \pi_0^*$
155
155
are defined implicitly by aligning these two equations.
156
156
<!-- #endregion -->
157
157
@@ -179,58 +179,58 @@ $$
179
179
Represent the previous equation system in terms of vectors and matrices as
180
180
181
181
$$
182
-
\vec \pi = \vec \mu + C \vec \pi^*
182
+
\pi = \mu + C \pi^*
183
183
$$ (eq:eq2)
184
184
185
185
where the $(T+1) \times (T+2)$ matrix $C$ is defined implicitly to align this equation with the preceding
186
186
equation system.
187
187
188
188
189
189
190
-
## Harvesting Returns from our Matrix Formulation
190
+
## Harvesting returns from our matrix formulation
191
191
192
192
193
-
We now have all of the ingredients we need to solve for $\vec \pi$ as
194
-
a function of $\vec \mu, \pi_0, \pi_0^*$.
193
+
We now have all of the ingredients we need to solve for $\pi$ as
194
+
a function of $\mu, \pi_0, \pi_0^*$.
195
195
196
196
Combine equations {eq}`eq:eq1`and {eq}`eq:eq2` to get
197
197
198
198
$$
199
199
\begin{align*}
200
-
A \vec \pi^* & = (1-\lambda) B \vec \pi + \vec \pi_0^* \cr
201
-
& = (1-\lambda) B \left[ \vec \mu + C \vec \pi^* \right] + \vec \pi_0^*
200
+
A \pi^* & = (1-\lambda) B \pi + \pi_0^* \cr
201
+
& = (1-\lambda) B \left[ \mu + C \pi^* \right] + \pi_0^*
202
202
\end{align*}
203
203
$$
204
204
205
205
which implies that
206
206
207
207
$$
208
-
\left[ A - (1-\lambda) B C \right] \vec \pi^* = (1-\lambda) B \vec \mu+ \vec \pi_0^*
208
+
\left[ A - (1-\lambda) B C \right] \pi^* = (1-\lambda) B \mu+ \pi_0^*
209
209
$$
210
210
211
211
Multiplying both sides of the above equation by the inverse of the matrix on the left side gives
212
212
213
213
$$
214
-
\vec \pi^* = \left[ A - (1-\lambda) B C \right]^{-1} \left[ (1-\lambda) B \vec \mu+ \vec \pi_0^* \right]
214
+
\pi^* = \left[ A - (1-\lambda) B C \right]^{-1} \left[ (1-\lambda) B \mu+ \pi_0^* \right]
215
215
$$ (eq:eq4)
216
216
217
-
Having solved equation {eq}`eq:eq4` for $\vec \pi^*$, we can use equation {eq}`eq:eq2` to solve for $\vec \pi$:
217
+
Having solved equation {eq}`eq:eq4` for $\pi^*$, we can use equation {eq}`eq:eq2` to solve for $\pi$:
218
218
219
219
$$
220
-
\vec \pi = \vec \mu + C \vec \pi^*
220
+
\pi = \mu + C \pi^*
221
221
$$
222
222
223
223
224
-
We have thus solved for two of the key endogenous time series determined by our model, namely, the sequence $\vec \pi^*$
225
-
of expected inflation rates and the sequence $\vec \pi$ of actual inflation rates.
224
+
We have thus solved for two of the key endogenous time series determined by our model, namely, the sequence $\pi^*$
225
+
of expected inflation rates and the sequence $\pi$ of actual inflation rates.
226
226
227
-
Knowing these, we can then quickly calculate the associated sequence $\vec p$ of the logarithm of the price level
227
+
Knowing these, we can then quickly calculate the associated sequence $p$ of the logarithm of the price level
228
228
from equation {eq}`eq:eqfiscth1`.
229
229
230
230
Let's fill in the details for this step.
231
231
<!-- #endregion -->
232
232
233
-
Since we now know $\vec \mu$ it is easy to compute $\vec m$.
233
+
Since we now know $\mu$ it is easy to compute $m$.
By assuring that the coefficient on $\pi_t$ is less than one in absolulte value, condition {eq}`eq:suffcond` assures stability of the dynamics of $\{\pi_t\}$ described by the last line of our string of deductions.
424
+
By assuring that the coefficient on $\pi_t$ is less than one in absolute value, condition {eq}`eq:suffcond` assures stability of the dynamics of $\{\pi_t\}$ described by the last line of our string of deductions.
429
425
430
426
The reader is free to study outcomes in examples that violate condition {eq}`eq:suffcond`.
Copy file name to clipboardExpand all lines: lectures/cagan_ree.md
+9-9Lines changed: 9 additions & 9 deletions
Original file line number
Diff line number
Diff line change
@@ -50,10 +50,10 @@ In those experiments, we'll encounter an instance of a ''velocity dividend'' tha
50
50
51
51
To facilitate using linear matrix algebra as our main mathematical tool, we'll use a finite horizon version of the model.
52
52
53
-
As in the {doc}`present values <pv>` and {doc}`consumption smoothing<cons_smooth>` lectures, the only linear algebra that we'll be using are matrix multplication and matrix inversion.
53
+
As in the {doc}`present values <pv>` and {doc}`consumption smoothing<cons_smooth>` lectures, the only linear algebra that we'll be using are matrix multiplication and matrix inversion.
54
54
55
55
56
-
## Structure of the Model
56
+
## Structure of the model
57
57
58
58
59
59
The model consists of
@@ -148,7 +148,7 @@ $$ (eq:pieq)
148
148
By multiplying both sides of equation {eq}`eq:pieq` by the inverse of the matrix on the left side, we can calculate
Equation {eq}`eq:mcum` shows that the log of the money supply at $t$ equals the log $m_0$ of the initial money supply
196
-
plus accumulation of rates of money growth between times $0$ and $t$.
195
+
Equation {eq}`eq:mcum` shows that the log of the money supply at $t$ equals the log of the initial money supply $m_0$
196
+
plus accumulation of rates of money growth between times $0$ and $T$.
197
197
198
198
## Continuation values
199
199
@@ -250,7 +250,7 @@ m0 = 1
250
250
251
251
+++ {"user_expressions": []}
252
252
253
-
Now we can solve the model to compute $\pi_t$, $m_t$ and $p_t$ for $t =1, \ldots, T+1$
253
+
Now we can solve the model to compute $\pi_t$, $m_t$ and $p_t$ for $t =1, \ldots, T+1$ using the matrix equation above
254
254
255
255
```{code-cell} ipython3
256
256
def solve(model):
@@ -371,13 +371,13 @@ reduction in $\mu$ has been foreseen.
371
371
372
372
#### Experiment 2: an unforeseen sudden stabilization
373
373
374
-
This experiment deviates a little bit from a pure version our "perfect foresight"
374
+
This experiment deviates a little bit from a pure version of our "perfect foresight"
375
375
assumption by assuming that a sudden permanent reduction in $\mu_t$ like that
376
376
analyzed in experiment 1 is completely unanticipated.
377
377
378
378
Such a completely unanticipated shock is popularly known as an "MIT shock".
379
379
380
-
The mental experiment involves switching at at time $T_1$ from an initial "continuation path" for $\{\mu_t, \pi_t\} $ to another path that involves a permanently lower inflation frate.
380
+
The mental experiment involves switching at time $T_1$ from an initial "continuation path" for $\{\mu_t, \pi_t\} $ to another path that involves a permanently lower inflation rate.
381
381
382
382
**Initial Path:** $\mu_t = \mu_0$ for all $t \geq 0$. So this path is for $\{\mu_t\}_{t=0}^\infty$; the associated
383
383
path for $\pi_t$ has $\pi_t = \mu_0$.
@@ -593,7 +593,7 @@ By letting money jump according to equation {eq}`eq:eqnmoneyjump` the monetary a
593
593
from **falling** at the moment that the unanticipated stabilization arrives.
594
594
595
595
In various research papers about stabilizations of high inflations, the jump in the money supply described by equation {eq}`eq:eqnmoneyjump` has been called
596
-
"the velocity dividend" that a government reaps from implementin a regime change that sustains a permanently lower inflation rate.
596
+
"the velocity dividend" that a government reaps from implementing a regime change that sustains a permanently lower inflation rate.
597
597
598
598
#### Technical Details about whether $p$ or $m$ jumps at $T_1$
0 commit comments