You signed in with another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You signed out in another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You switched accounts on another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.Dismiss alert
Copy file name to clipboardExpand all lines: lectures/cagan_adaptive.md
+4-4Lines changed: 4 additions & 4 deletions
Original file line number
Diff line number
Diff line change
@@ -11,9 +11,9 @@ kernelspec:
11
11
name: python3
12
12
---
13
13
14
-
# A Monetarist Theory of Price Levels with Adaptive Expectations
14
+
# Monetarist Theory of Price Levels with Adaptive Expectations
15
15
16
-
## Introduction
16
+
## Overview
17
17
18
18
19
19
This lecture is a sequel or prequel to the lecture {doc}`cagan_ree`.
@@ -22,7 +22,7 @@ We'll use linear algebra to do some experiments with an alternative "monetarist
22
22
23
23
Like the model in {doc}`cagan_ree`, the model asserts that when a government persistently spends more than it collects in taxes and prints money to finance the shortfall, it puts upward pressure on the price level and generates persistent inflation.
24
24
25
-
Instead of the "perfect foresight" or "rational expectations" version of the model in {doc}`cagan_ree`, our model in the present lecture is an "adaptive expectations" version of a model that Philip Cagan {cite}`Cagan` used to study the monetary dynamics of hyperinflations.
25
+
Instead of the "perfect foresight" or "rational expectations" version of the model in {doc}`cagan_ree`, our model in the present lecture is an "adaptive expectations" version of a model that {cite}`Cagan` used to study the monetary dynamics of hyperinflations.
26
26
27
27
It combines these components:
28
28
@@ -79,7 +79,7 @@ $$
79
79
$$ (eq:eqpipi)
80
80
81
81
We assume that the expected rate of inflation $\pi_t^*$ is governed
82
-
by the following adaptive expectations scheme proposed by {cite}`Friedman1956` and {citet}`Cagan`:
82
+
by the following adaptive expectations scheme proposed by {cite}`Friedman1956` and {cite}`Cagan`:
Copy file name to clipboardExpand all lines: lectures/laffer_adaptive.md
+16-5Lines changed: 16 additions & 5 deletions
Original file line number
Diff line number
Diff line change
@@ -34,6 +34,8 @@ $$
34
34
35
35
that we adopted in lectures {doc}`money_inflation` and lectures {doc}`money_inflation_nonlinear`, we'll now assume that $\pi_t^*$ is determined by the adaptive expectations hypothesis described in equation {eq}`eq:adaptex` reported below.
36
36
37
+
38
+
37
39
We shall discover that changing our hypothesis about expectations formation in this way will change some our findings and leave others intact. In particular, we shall discover that
38
40
39
41
@@ -45,6 +47,18 @@ These more plausible comparative dynamics underly the "old time religion" that s
45
47
"inflation is always and everwhere caused by government deficits".
46
48
47
49
50
+
These issues were studyied by {cite}`bruno1990seigniorage`.
51
+
52
+
Their purpose was to reverse what they thought were counter intuitive
53
+
predictions of their model under rational expectations (i.e., perfect foresight in this context)
54
+
by dropping rational expectations and instead assuming that people form expectations about future inflation rates according to the "adaptive expectations" scheme {eq}`eq:adaptex` described below.
55
+
56
+
```{note}
57
+
{cite}`sargent1989least` had studied another way of selecting stationary equilibrium that involved replacing rational expectations with a model of learning via least squares regression.
58
+
{cite}`marcet2003recurrent` and {cite}`sargent2009conquest` extended that work and applied it to study recurrent high-inflation episodes in Latin America.
We are now equipped to compute time series starting from different $p_{-1}, \pi_{-1}^*$ settings, analogous to those in the this XXXX **money_inflation** lecture.
395
+
We are now equipped to compute time series starting from different $p_{-1}, \pi_{-1}^*$ settings, analogous to those in this lecture {doc}`money_inflation` and this lecture {doc}`money_inflation_nonlinear`.
382
396
383
-
HUMPHREY -- MARCH 16 MODIFICATION OF CHOICE OF "PERTURBED" INITIAL CONDITIONS $p_{-1}, \pi_{-1}^*$
384
-
385
-
PLEASE RESTRICT THE PERTURBATIONS AS FOLLOWS.
386
397
387
398
Now we'll study how outcomes unfold when we start $p_{-1}, \pi_{-1}^*$ away from a stationary point of the dynamic Laffer curve, i.e., away from either $\pi_u$ or $ \pi_l$.
388
399
@@ -391,7 +402,7 @@ To construct a perturbation pair $\check p_{-1}, \check \pi_{-1}^*$we'll impleme
391
402
* set $\check \pi_{-1}^* $ not equal to one of the stationary points $\pi_u$ or $ \pi_l$.
392
403
* set $\check p_{-1} = m_0 + \alpha \check \pi_{-1}^*$
393
404
394
-
Do this "cautiously" around each of the fixed points $\pi_u$ or $ \pi_l$.
Copy file name to clipboardExpand all lines: lectures/money_inflation.md
+63-9Lines changed: 63 additions & 9 deletions
Original file line number
Diff line number
Diff line change
@@ -13,7 +13,7 @@ kernelspec:
13
13
14
14
+++ {"user_expressions": []}
15
15
16
-
# Money Supplies and Price Levels
16
+
# Money Financed Government Deficits and Price Levels
17
17
18
18
+++ {"user_expressions": []}
19
19
@@ -22,39 +22,40 @@ kernelspec:
22
22
This lecture extends and modifies the model in this lecture {doc}`cagan_ree` by modifying the
23
23
law of motion that governed the supply of money.
24
24
25
-
In particular, this lecture describes a theory of price level variations that consists of two components
25
+
The model in this lecture consists of two components
26
26
27
27
* a demand function for money
28
28
* a law of motion for the supply of money
29
29
30
30
The demand function describes the public's demand for "real balances", defined as the ratio of nominal money balances to the price level
31
31
32
+
* it assumes that the demand for real balance today varies inversely with the rate of inflation that the public forecasts to prevail between today and tomorrow
33
+
* it assumes that the public's forecast of that rate of inflation is perfect
34
+
32
35
The law of motion for the supply of money assumes that the government prints money to finance government expenditures
33
36
34
37
Our model equates the demand for money to the supply at each time $t \geq 0$.
35
38
36
39
Equality between those demands and supply gives in a **dynamic** model in which money supply
37
-
and price level **sequences** are simultaneously determined by a special set of simultaneous linear equations.
40
+
and price level **sequences** are simultaneously determined by a set of simultaneous linear equations.
38
41
39
42
These equations take the form of what are often called vector linear **difference equations**.
40
43
41
-
In this lecture, we'll roll up our sleeves and solve those equations in a couple of different ways.
42
-
43
-
As we'll see, Python is good at solving them.
44
+
In this lecture, we'll roll up our sleeves and solve those equations in two different ways.
44
45
45
46
46
47
(One of the methods for solving vector linear difference equations will take advantage of a decomposition of a matrix that is studied in this lecture {doc}`eigen_I`.)
47
48
48
-
In this lecture we will encounter these concepts
49
+
In this lecture we will encounter these concepts from macroeconomics:
49
50
50
51
* an **inflation tax** that a government gathers by printing paper or electronic money
51
52
* a dynamic **Laffer curve** in the inflation tax rate that has two stationary equilibria
52
53
* perverse dynamics under rational expectations in which the system converges to the higher stationary inflation tax rate
53
-
* a peculiar comparative stationary-state analysis connected with that stationary inflation rate that assert that inflation can be **reduced** by running **higher** government deficits
54
+
* a peculiar comparative stationary-state outcome connected with that stationary inflation rate: it asserts that inflation can be **reduced** by running **higher** government deficits, i.e., by raising more resources by printing money.
54
55
55
56
The same qualitive outcomes prevail in this lecture {doc}`money_inflation_nonlinear` that studies a nonlinear version of the model in this lecture.
56
57
57
-
These outcomes will set the stage for the analysis of this lecture {doc}`laffer_adaptive` that studies a nonlinear version of the present model that uses a version of "adaptive expectations" instead of rational expectations.
58
+
These outcomes set the stage for the analysis to be presented in this lecture {doc}`laffer_adaptive` that studies a nonlinear version of the present model; it assumes a version of "adaptive expectations" instead of rational expectations.
58
59
59
60
That lecture will show that
60
61
@@ -203,10 +204,12 @@ Notice that both $R_t = \frac{p_t}{p_{t+1}}$ and $b_t = \frac{m_{t+1}}{p_t} $ ar
203
204
204
205
To compute a steady state, we seek gross rates of return on currency $\bar R, \bar b$ that satisfy steady-state versions of both the government budget constraint and the demand function for real balances:
205
206
207
+
$$
206
208
\begin{aligned}
207
209
g & = \bar b ( 1 - \bar R) \cr
208
210
\bar b & = \gamma_1- \gamma_2 \bar R^{-1}
209
211
\end{aligned}
212
+
$$
210
213
211
214
Together these equations imply
212
215
@@ -952,3 +955,54 @@ Please notice that for $m_t$ and $p_t$, we have used log scales for the coordin
952
955
953
956
Using log scales allows us to spot distinct constant limiting gross rates of growth ${R_u}^{-1}$ and
954
957
${R_l}^{-1}$ by eye.
958
+
959
+
960
+
## Peculiar stationary outcomes
961
+
962
+
As promised at the start of this lecture, we have encountered these concepts from macroeconomics:
963
+
964
+
* an **inflation tax** that a government gathers by printing paper or electronic money
965
+
* a dynamic **Laffer curve** in the inflation tax rate that has two stationary equilibria
966
+
967
+
Staring at the paths of rates of return on the price level in figure {numref}`R0_path` and price levels in {numref}`p0_path` show indicate that almost all paths converge to the **higher** inflation tax rate displayed in the stationary state Laffer curve displayed in figure {numref}`infl_tax`.
968
+
969
+
Thus, we have indeed discovered what we earlier called "perverse" dynamics under rational expectations in which the system converges to the higher of two possible stationary inflation tax rates.
970
+
971
+
Those dynamics are "perverse" not only in the sense that they imply that the monetary and fiscal authorities that have chosen to finance government expenditures eventually impose a higher inflation tax than required to finance government expenditures, but because of the following "counterintuitive" situation that we can deduce by staring at the stationary state Laffer curve displayed in figure {numref}`infl_tax`:
972
+
973
+
* the figure indicates that inflation can be **reduced** by running **higher** government deficits, i.e., by raising more resources through printing money.
974
+
975
+
976
+
```{note}
977
+
The same qualitive outcomes prevail in this lecture {doc}`money_inflation_nonlinear` that studies a nonlinear version of the model in this lecture.
978
+
```
979
+
980
+
981
+
## Equilibrium selection criterion
982
+
983
+
We have discovered that as a model of price level paths or model is **incomplete** because there is a continuum of "equilibrium" paths for $\{m_{t+1}, p_t\}_{t=0}^\infty$ that are consistent with the demand for real balances always equaling the supply.
984
+
985
+
986
+
Through application of our computational methods 1 and 2, we have learned that this continuum can be indexed by choice of one of two scalars:
987
+
988
+
* for computational method 1, $R_0$
989
+
* for computational method 2, $p_0$
990
+
991
+
To apply our model, we have somehow to **complete** it by **selecting** an equilibrium path from among the continuum of possible paths.
992
+
993
+
We discovered that
994
+
995
+
* all but one of the equilibrium paths converge to limits in which the higher of two possible stationary inflation tax prevails
996
+
* there is a unique equilibrium path associated with "plausible" statements about how reductions in government deficits affect a stationary inflation rate
997
+
998
+
On grounds of plausibility, we recommend following many macroeconomists in selecting the unique equilibrium that converges to the lower stationary inflation tax rate.
999
+
1000
+
As we shall see, we shall accept this recommendation in lecture {doc}`unpleasant`.
1001
+
1002
+
In lecture, {doc}`laffer_adaptive`, we shall explore how {cite}`bruno1990seigniorage` and others justified this in other ways.
REQUEST FOR HUMPRHEY: PLEASE MAKE A CAPTION BELOW THE ABOVE GRAPH THAT WE CAN REFER TO AS WE DO
418
+
THE LECTURE MONEY_INFLATION.MD
419
+
420
+
IF WE ZOOM, I CAN EXPLAIN QUICKLY.
421
+
422
+
Staring at the paths of price levels in {numref}`p0_pathnonlin` show indicate that almost all paths converge to the **higher** inflation tax rate displayed in the stationary state Laffer curve. %displayed in figure {numref}`infl_tax`.
423
+
424
+
Thus, we have indeed discovered what we earlier called "perverse" dynamics under rational expectations in which the system converges to the higher of two possible stationary inflation tax rates.
425
+
426
+
Those dynamics are "perverse" not only in the sense that they imply that the monetary and fiscal authorities that have chosen to finance government expenditures eventually impose a higher inflation tax than required to finance government expenditures, but because of the following "counterintuitive" situation that we can deduce by staring at the stationary state Laffer curve displayed in figure {numref}`infl_tax`:
427
+
428
+
* the figure indicates that inflation can be **reduced** by running **higher** government deficits, i.e., by raising more resources through printing money.
429
+
430
+
431
+
```{note}
432
+
The same qualitive outcomes prevail in this lecture {doc}`money_inflation` that studies a linear version of the model in this lecture`.
0 commit comments