You signed in with another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You signed out in another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You switched accounts on another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.Dismiss alert
Copy file name to clipboardExpand all lines: lectures/cons_smooth.md
+25-32Lines changed: 25 additions & 32 deletions
Original file line number
Diff line number
Diff line change
@@ -17,9 +17,9 @@ kernelspec:
17
17
## Overview
18
18
19
19
20
-
In this lecture, we'll study a famous model of the "consumption function" that Milton Friedman {cite}`Friedman1956` and Robert Hall {cite}`Hall1978`) proposed to fit some empirical data patterns that the original Keynesian consumption function described in this quantecon lecture {doc}`geometric series <geom_series>` missed.
20
+
In this lecture, we'll study a famous model of the "consumption function" that Milton Friedman {cite}`Friedman1956` and Robert Hall {cite}`Hall1978`) proposed to fit some empirical data patterns that the original Keynesian consumption function described in this QuantEcon lecture {doc}`geometric series <geom_series>` missed.
21
21
22
-
In this lecture, we'll study what is often called the "consumption-smoothing model" using matrix multiplication and matrix inversion, the same tools that we used in this quantecon lecture {doc}`present values <pv>`.
22
+
In this lecture, we'll study what is often called the "consumption-smoothing model" using matrix multiplication and matrix inversion, the same tools that we used in this QuantEcon lecture {doc}`present values <pv>`.
23
23
24
24
Formulas presented in {doc}`present value formulas<pv>` are at the core of the consumption smoothing model because we shall use them to define a consumer's "human wealth".
25
25
@@ -29,7 +29,7 @@ and that standard asset-pricing formulas could be applied to compute a person's
29
29
''non-financial wealth'' that capitalizes the earnings stream.
30
30
31
31
```{note}
32
-
As we'll see in this quantecon lecture {doc}`equalizing difference model <equalizing_difference>`,
32
+
As we'll see in this QuantEcon lecture {doc}`equalizing difference model <equalizing_difference>`,
33
33
Milton Friedman had used this idea in his PhD thesis at Columbia University,
34
34
eventually published as {cite}`kuznets1939incomes` and {cite}`friedman1954incomes`.
35
35
```
@@ -58,21 +58,14 @@ The consumer faces a gross interest rate of $R >1$ that is constant over time, a
58
58
59
59
To set up the model, let
60
60
61
-
* $T \geq 2$ be a positive integer that constitutes a time-horizon
62
-
63
-
* $y = \{y_t\}_{t=0}^T$ be an exogenous sequence of non-negative non-financial incomes $y_t$
64
-
65
-
* $a = \{a_t\}_{t=0}^{T+1}$ be a sequence of financial wealth
66
-
67
-
* $c = \{c_t\}_{t=0}^T$ be a sequence of non-negative consumption rates
68
-
69
-
* $R \geq 1$ be a fixed gross one period rate of return on financial assets
70
-
71
-
* $\beta \in (0,1)$ be a fixed discount factor
72
-
61
+
* $T \geq 2$ be a positive integer that constitutes a time-horizon.
62
+
* $y = \{y_t\}_{t=0}^T$ be an exogenous sequence of non-negative non-financial incomes $y_t$.
63
+
* $a = \{a_t\}_{t=0}^{T+1}$ be a sequence of financial wealth.
64
+
* $c = \{c_t\}_{t=0}^T$ be a sequence of non-negative consumption rates.
65
+
* $R \geq 1$ be a fixed gross one period rate of return on financial assets.
66
+
* $\beta \in (0,1)$ be a fixed discount factor.
73
67
* $a_0$ be a given initial level of financial assets
74
-
75
-
* $a_{T+1} \geq 0$ be a terminal condition on final assets
68
+
* $a_{T+1} \geq 0$ be a terminal condition on final assets.
76
69
77
70
The sequence of financial wealth $a$ is to be determined by the model.
78
71
@@ -83,7 +76,7 @@ We require it to satisfy two **boundary conditions**:
83
76
84
77
The **terminal condition** $a_{T+1} \geq 0$ requires that the consumer not leave the model in debt.
85
78
86
-
(We'll soon see that a utility maximizing consumer won't **want** to die leaving positive assets, so she'll arrange her affairs to make
79
+
(We'll soon see that a utility maximizing consumer won't want to die leaving positive assets, so she'll arrange her affairs to make
87
80
$a_{T+1} = 0$.)
88
81
89
82
The consumer faces a sequence of budget constraints that constrains sequences $(y, c, a)$
@@ -94,7 +87,7 @@ $$ (eq:a_t)
94
87
95
88
Equations {eq}`eq:a_t` constitute $T+1$ such budget constraints, one for each $t=0, 1, \ldots, T$.
96
89
97
-
Given a sequence $y$ of non-financial incomes, a large set of **pairs** $(a, c)$ of (financial wealth, consumption) sequences satisfy the sequence of budget constraints {eq}`eq:a_t`.
90
+
Given a sequence $y$ of non-financial incomes, a large set of pairs $(a, c)$ of (financial wealth, consumption) sequences satisfy the sequence of budget constraints {eq}`eq:a_t`.
98
91
99
92
Our model has the following logical flow.
100
93
@@ -116,7 +109,7 @@ with the exogenous non-financial income stream $y$, the initial financial asset
116
109
117
110
In general, there are **many** budget feasible consumption paths $c$.
118
111
119
-
Among all budget-feasible consumption paths, which one **should** a consumer want?
112
+
Among all budget-feasible consumption paths, which one should a consumer want?
120
113
121
114
122
115
To answer this question, we shall eventually evaluate alternative budget feasible consumption paths $c$ using the following utility functional or **welfare criterion**:
@@ -131,7 +124,7 @@ where $g_1 > 0, g_2 > 0$.
131
124
132
125
When $\beta R \approx 1$, the fact that the utility function $g_1 c_t - \frac{g_2}{2} c_t^2$ has diminishing marginal utility imparts a preference for consumption that is very smooth.
133
126
134
-
Indeed, we shall see that when $\beta R = 1$ (a condition assumed by Milton Friedman {cite}`Friedman1956` and Robert Hall {cite}`Hall1978`), criterion {eq}`welfare` assigns higher welfare to **smoother** consumption paths.
127
+
Indeed, we shall see that when $\beta R = 1$ (a condition assumed by Milton Friedman {cite}`Friedman1956` and Robert Hall {cite}`Hall1978`), criterion {eq}`welfare` assigns higher welfare to smoother consumption paths.
135
128
136
129
By **smoother** we mean as close as possible to being constant over time.
137
130
@@ -147,11 +140,11 @@ We create a Python **namedtuple** to store these parameters with default values.
Human or non-financial wealth at time $0$ is evidently just the present value of the consumer's non-financial income stream $y$.
169
162
170
-
Formally it very much resembles the asset price that we computed in this quantecon lecture {doc}`present values <pv>`.
163
+
Formally it very much resembles the asset price that we computed in this QuantEcon lecture {doc}`present values <pv>`.
171
164
172
165
Indeed, this is why Milton Friedman called it "human capital".
173
166
@@ -185,7 +178,7 @@ $$ (eq:budget_intertemp)
185
178
186
179
Equation {eq}`eq:budget_intertemp` says that the present value of the consumption stream equals the sum of finanical and non-financial (or human) wealth.
187
180
188
-
Robert Hall {cite}`Hall1978` showed that when $\beta R = 1$, a condition Milton Friedman had also assumed, it is "optimal" for a consumer to **smooth consumption** by setting
181
+
Robert Hall {cite}`Hall1978` showed that when $\beta R = 1$, a condition Milton Friedman had also assumed, it is "optimal" for a consumer to smooth consumption by setting
The consumption-smoothing model of Milton Friedman {cite}`Friedman1956` and Robert Hall {cite}`Hall1978`) is a cornerstone of modern macro that has important ramifications for the size of the Keynesian "fiscal policy multiplier" described briefly in
666
-
quantecon lecture {doc}`geometric series <geom_series>`.
659
+
QuantEcon lecture {doc}`geometric series <geom_series>`.
667
660
668
661
In particular, it **lowers** the government expenditure multiplier relative to one implied by
669
662
the original Keynesian consumption function presented in {doc}`geometric series <geom_series>`.
0 commit comments